Reform in stride: Rural Change 1984
Reform |
This article is a shortened version of a talk given in
After the initial land reform in
To understand the impact of this new system on Chinese agriculture, you have to have a picture of
The responsibility system is in some ways a revival of the policy called san zi yi bao
(roughly, three freedoms -- one contract), instituted in 1962 after the
debacle of the Great Freedoms were freedom to enlarge the area of
private plots, to expand free markets, and to foster small
profit-making enterprises, and the one contract was the contract made
by each individual family for set quotas of grain to be delivered at
state prices.
Throwback to the 1960s?
This
system spread very widely in the early 1960s and offers some
interesting parallels with today. Of course, freedom to expand private
plots pales into insignificance when almost the whole of the land is
contracted privately as now. The expansion of markets and the setting
up of individual sidelines for profit are the most important adjuncts
to the whole policy, but the heart of it remains contracting out the
land family by family.
When the contracts first started, they were temporary and
indefinite in term. Later the term was set at three years. Now
contracts are for fifteen years, with inheritance rights. If the
contractor dies within fifteen years, descendants can inherit the
contract and carry it through. This is all but universal in
Other forms are more complicated, often entailing an obligation
to turn over grain to the local village office. This grain earns work
points, and the contractor gets back a share, with cash distribution
once or twice a year. In yet another form, only part of the land is
contracted. The community reserves the rest and each peasant agrees to
work so many days on this public land. There are also variations where
groups can contract. And sometimes the amount contracted is determined
by the number in the family, sometimes by the number of ablebodied
workers in a family. Most variations revolve around contracting
resources out to the family as a production unit.
The big advantage of contracting from the point of view of the authorities
is that it automatically solves the question of reward according to
work performed. Each family works on its own resources, and whatever
the members raise reflects the work they have put in. The system does
not need much planning; it does not take much organizing; it does not
take much leadership. There are no accounts to keep, not a lot of
meetings to be held -- each family takes care of itself. Also, no one
is responsible for poor results except the contractor. The authorities
simply give the resources to the individuals and tell them to enrich
themselves, and if in five years they are not rich it is their own
fault. Certainly no one can blame the authorities.
Fostering Specialization
Contracting goes along with a wide-open market, which is very
important. For instance, a contractor may have a contract to deliver a
certain amount of grain, but he does not have to raise that grain
himself: he can raise cotton or other crops, whatever he thinks is more
profitable, and can buy the grain from somebody else and deliver that
to the government to meet the grain quota. That has become quite common
in some places, to the point where grain production has dropped off
sharply and new regulations have to be established requiring people to
raise the grain they owe.
The market has stimulated all sorts of small sidelines. Under
the commune system, where it was badly led, handicrafts were often
discouraged and special products were also discouraged. People did not
feel free to go to market. With no outlet for the things they made,
they just stopped making them. Now with a wide-open market people can
start making whatever they want and generally find an outlet for it. So
people are specializing in all sorts of things, even strange ones: one
peasant is raising scorpions, for example. A lot of people have gone
into beekeeping. China is a land of great variety, multiple resources,
and remarkable ingenuity and although I do not think that the
cooperative system by necessity suppressed this ingenuity -- in many
cases it promoted it -- certainly the new policy has unleashed a great
deal of individual creativity.
Along with the free market goes the freedom to set up individual
or cooperative enterprises for profit. Shareholding industrial
cooperatives are much in order today, and many people are pooling
capital and setting up enterprises that resemble joint stock companies.
Along with this goes the right to hire and fire people. At first the
government set limits on the number of employees permitted in a private
enterprise. For a while it was said you could hire six or eight people;
then you could hire as many people as you wanted as long as they were
family members -- not a very stringent restriction since in many
Chinese communities everyone has the same surname and could be called a
relative. Now even those restrictions have gone out the window and
hiring is essentially unlimited.
The tremendous increase in marketing has provided an income for
large numbers of people as peddlers and sellers as well. You see things
you have not seen for twenty years in
Finally, people now have the right to buy and own productive
equipment privately, like tractors or machinery, trucks, processing
equipment, and so on. Such ownership is now very widespread.
Probably 98 percent of all the land in
Economic Results
While I do not think grain production has increased as much in
the last few years as has been claimed, clearly grain is not in short
supply. The price of free market grain is dropping and approaching that
of state grain, which would not happen if there was any major
shortage. Furthermore, some people are feeding a great deal of
livestock -- 12,000 hens or 125 pigs per family --
something
they could not do if grain were not available. The situation is
particularly good with coarse grains such as maize, sorghum, and so on,
which people do not like to eat. In the past most people had to eat
these, but now they eat wheat and rice and feed more coarse grains to
livestock.
But in some places there has actually been a big decline in
grain production; people have shifted to other things or even abandoned
land. In parts of
At the same time, "economic crops" have really shot up; cotton
production has doubled, and oil seeds and other special crops such as
fruit and vegetables have shown significant increase. Yields in
But while these good results are quite well publicized, other
consequences are less well known. One of these is the fragmentation of
the land, which is quite extraordinary. One of the most promising
things in the collective system in terms of future modernization was
the fact that the land had been put together in a very practical way.
Fields were large; machines, if they had them, could have gone to work
easily in
One reason for this of course is that there are twice as many
families on the land. Another reason is that officials tried to do the
contracting fairly. This meant that almost every family in the village
got a piece of each quality of land. Every family also got a strip of
the near field, and a strip of the far field, so that each big piece
was cut into hundreds of small strips. Since the original fields were
big, and access is necessary to each small strip, they gave each family
a piece stretching from one road to the next, which means a long and
narrow strip. The same area might be reasonable if it were shaped as a
square, but all these strips cause great difficulties. Many are so
narrow that even a cart can't go down them, which means that everything
has to be carried in and out on a carrying pole. Also, there are
endless quarrels about strip widths and cheating: "I robbed a furrow
from you and you robbed a furrow from me." The courts are loaded with
lawsuits concerning land use and irrigation rights and so on.
Fragmentation has not affected yields that much yet, because
peasants are still farming with hoes, after all, and it really doesn't
matter with hoe agriculture whether the strip is a yard wide or 10
acres in one bloc -- except that it involves much more labor. Peasants
are just working harder, working more hours, putting in more effort;
there is a general speedup in agriculture and this extraordinary effort
is maintaining yields or even raising them.
Destruction of Resources
The long-term destruction of resources that belong to the
collective is one of the worst results of the new system. In many
cases, collective assets were simply broken up and sold to individual
bidders; when it became clear that the collective's property was going
to be contracted out, people came and dismantled whatever belonged to
them jointly, including the headquarters, school, any publicly owned
machinery, and so on. They took window frames out, doors off, and the
beams out of the roof. In
Destruction has also increased sharply in terms of the
environment. Trees have been cut down in great numbers, and around
I've traveled on the same train north from
When you raise questions about these ravages people tell you it
is a matter of controlling abuses, resolving them with new laws and
alert police action. But some of these people are getting so prosperous
they will be able to defy the laws and pay off the police.
Hired Hands Make It Work
The whole thrust of the new policy is supposed to enable the
socialist principle of distribution, "to each according to his work,"
to be realized. But since each family can contract more capital goods,
and even more land than they can operate themselves, they can hire
others to do the work. People told me proudly of a man in northern
The size of some of the new private enterprises is constantly
growing. The paper showed a picture of the first peasant in
Another peasant mentioned in the press was making sausage. He
had four family members. But his sausage business grew so much that a
few months ago he hired four skilled workers, each of whom brought an
apprentice. By any definition of the past, if a family hires more labor
than it contributes itself, it is a rich peasant family.
At the start, of course, the contractor maintains the old
relationships. The wage equivalent of the work-points people used to
earn is paid by the contractor, who takes a modest amount as his own
salary. But no one has control over later developments. Long Bow had
six gardens -- each of them about six acres -- with fifteen people
sharing work and income. The gardens were contracted to the highest
bidder and then each contractor hired fifteen people to do the work at
well below standard wages.
In addition, there is an enormous growth in the number of
middlemen or commission merchants. These people are in control of
resources and handle transportation. For instance, there is a man who
has responsibility for moving all the cement out of the cement mill in
Long Bow and bringing in all the raw materials. He hires the carts that
haul the goods. If the cart is local -- that is to say, if it belongs
to a village resident, he gets 10 percent of the earnings of each load.
If it is not local, he gets 20 percent. A man like this is making big
money.
The authorities claim that peasant income has now doubled --
quite an achievement. But the figure may not have been corrected for
inflation, because it is clear that this period has seen a sharp rise
in prices as well -- city people are complaining about food prices
being much higher.
What is involved in all of this is not just income
differentiation but class differentiation. Those who get rich first
preempt the high ground and end up exploiting those who have lagged
behind. There is also something troubling going on with regard to the
so-called free market. In one case a gang took over a tomato market
where peasants were bringing in fresh tomatoes, forcing the peasants to
sell their produce behind a building and then selling directly to the
people in the market themselves. I'm not sure how widespread such
strongarm methods are, but they are ugly, and they are expanding.
Any system that disregards limits on the amount of resources
that can be contracted does not end up distributing rewards based on
work.
performed.
What develops is a system that bases rewards on the amount of
productive resources contracted. The capital controlled soon outweighs
the work done.
Gruesome Customs
The new system also radically affects the quality of life: the
more the system reflects the old economic relations or turns toward
traditional economic relations, the more traditional culture and
customs revive. This was brought home to us rather gruesomely in Long
Bow by the death and burial of two old peasants last August.
Ordinarily, people bury the dead as soon as possible, particularly in
August! But now almost everyone that has a death in the family goes to
the soothsayer or oracle in the village for a proper date for the
burial. It is important not only where but when you bury a person, the
stars have to be right. And this oracle turns out to be someone who was
once sort of regarded as the village fool; they called him ba mao,
which means "eight dimes" (since there are ten dimes in a dollar, eight
means not all there). Somehow he inherited a book of oracles from his
grandfather and he is now the chief seer of the village.
This fellow told the bereaved they should bury the body eight
days after the person died. On the day of the burial -- they don't bury
the body till
I also saw the revival of many traditional entertainments. There
were 7 million people involved in amateur drama in
More Labor Leaving Agriculture
One thing that interests me particularly is the enormous shift
of labor out of agriculture that the new policy has brought about. I
have long argued for mechanization, and over the years was always told,
"We have too many people; how could we possibly do it?" And of course
my view was that they should begin in places such as Long Bow which are
suburban and where there is alternative employment for the released
labor, and where the community is prosperous. Begin there, and work
outward to solve the technical problems. It would progressively spread
and maybe 20 percent would do it first and another 10 percent later,
and then another 20 percent, and so on over many years. But no one ever
listened to those arguments. And now the responsibility system has
thrown about 30 percent of the people off the land in one year: the
people who did not contract land. Of that 30 percent, only half have
found anything else to do as of January 1984, so there is an enormous
displacement based not on technical advance but simply on economic and
social policy. No conceivable mechanization plan could have done that
on that scale in that time. Say there are 300 million people engaged in
farming in
All of this recalls some of the problems that emerged with the New Democracy program in
Next: The situation in the grasslands
Back to the Contents page