1993 review of "Imperialism, pioneer of Capitalism" - Bill Warren's book, Imperialism, Pioneer of Capitalism, performs a useful service by refuting much of the mythology that the left has embraced in the name of 'anti- imperialism'.
REFUTING "ANTI IMPERIALIST' MYTHS
A Review of Warren's Imperialism, Pioneer of Capitalism.
This article was originally published in September 1993 in the journal "Red Politics"
David McMullen (1993)
Bill Warren's book, Imperialism, Pioneer of Capitalism, performs a
useful service by refuting much of the mythology that the left has
embraced in the name of 'anti- imperialism'. However, on the other hand, he
manages to create his own brand of confusion. He does this, firstly, by
blaming Lenin's Imperialism the Highest Stage of Capitalism for many of
the left's erroneous views.
And secondly, he is so busy extolling the historical mission of capitalism, that no effort is devoted to discussing how capitalism is an obstacle to human development and is becoming increasingly obsolete. Neverthelsee, despite these shortcomings it is the myth shattering quality of the book that predominates.
Warren begins by reminding us of the basics of a Marxist attitude to capitalism:
(a) It is an advance in all respects on earlier forms of society.
(b) It develops the productive forces and society generally, so creating the necessary material or objective conditions for future communist society. This development also generates the contradictions which lead to capitalism's revolutionary overthrow.
The following passage from the Communist Manifesto that Warren quotes (Warren 1980, p 11) says it all.
The bourgeoisie cannot exist without constantly revolutionizing the instruments of production, and thereby the relations of production, and with them the whole relations of society. Conservation of the old modes of production in unaltered form, was, on the contrary, the first condition of existence for all earlier industrial classes. Constant revolutionizing of production, uninterrupted disturbance of all social conditions, everlasting uncertainty and agitation distinguish the bourgeois epoch from all earlier ones. All fixed, fact-frozen relations, with their train of ancient and venerable prejudices and opinions, are swept away, all new-formed ones becomes antiquated before they can ossify. All that is solid melts into air, all that is holy is profaned, and man is at last compelled to face with sober senses his real condition of life, and his
relations with his kind. (Marx and Engels, 1968, pp 34-5.)
This approach to capitalism is at total variance to that prevailing in
the "left', The usual practice is to bemoan the development of
capitalist productive relations and productive forces, and to cherish
the things that capitalism is destroying. A few examples might clarify
this point.
(1) Increased economic concentration and the destruction of the
petty bourgeoisie. A classic case of the left's response is its
bemoaning such things as agribusiness, supermarkets and fastfood
chains.
(2) The increasing internationalisation of capital and the
division
of labor, which increases human intercourse on a world scale and lays
the basis for a global society. This is denounced for destroying our
independence and national heritage and placing us at the mercy of
the multinationals.
(3) The destruction of cherished skills by new technologies
(cherished, that is, by trendy left sociologists). To a Marxist,
technological development is eliminating the technical division of
labor which is the material basis of class society. In other words we
are moving to a situation where you will have an educated and versatile
workforce, on the one hand, and on the other hand, processes of
production in which all types of activities can be performed equally by
all members of the workforce.
(4) The erosion of traditional culture and social bonds.
Traditional
life tends to be romanticized, compared with soulless modern living We
have lost something. On the other hand, to a Marxist the neuroses and
instability of modern life are infinitely superior to the narrow
mindless certainty and security of days gone by.
So given that capitalism is a social advance and creates the conditions for social revolution, how are we to view European colonial expansion into pre-capitalist societies?
Warren cites, by way of example, Marx's recognition of the historically progressive role of Britain's penetration of India.
England, it is true, in causing a social revolution in Hindoostan, was actuated by the vilest interests, and was stupid in her manner of enforcing them. But that is not the question. The question is, can mankind fulfill its destiny without a fundamental revolution in the social state of Asia? If not, whatever may have been the crimes of England, she was the unconscious tool of history in bringing about the revolution. (S. Avineri (ed.) pp 93-94.)
Not long afterwards, Marx wrote as follows:
England has to fulfill a double mission in India: one destructive, the other regenerating - the annihilation of old Asiatic society, and the laying of the material foundations of Western society in Asia (S. Avineri (ed.) pp 132.)
On the destruction side, they broke up or seriously undermined much
of the existing social fabric and pre- capitalist modes of production.
On the construction side, political unity was greatly enhanced by the
British sword (mainly in the hands of local recruits), telegraph and
railways, and embryonic industrialization began to emerge.
It is appropriate that the anti-colonial struggles of the twentieth
century have not simply been directed at expelling the foreign
oppressor. Rarely was the struggle simply one of returning to the days
before colonial rule. For example, the struggle for independence in
India was not directed at restoring the Mogul empire and independence
in Africa did not mean returning to tribal hunter gathering or slash
and burn societies.
In some cases such as in China, the revolution was directed at the total destruction of the traditional conditions that predated colonialism such as the remnants of feudalism. Even where independence from colonialism was not accompanied by fundamental social revolutions, the essential aspect of decolonisation was the establishment of a modern state, and the first steps towards a modern economy.
In the case of Czarist Russia, the modern industrial sector, which spawned the proletariat in the two decades prior to 1914, was primarily the product of foreign investment. At no stage did the Bolsheviks target this foreign ownership as something to be abhorred, an interesting point in the light of the economic nationalist position adopted by most of the Australian left.
To quote Warren:
Between 1896 and 1900 a quarter of all new companies formed were foreign, and by 1900 foreign capital accounted for 28% of the total. By 1914 the proportion had risen to 33%. Foreign capital controlled 45% of Russia's oil output, 54% of her iron output, 50% of her chemical industry, 74% of her coal output. More than half of the capital of the six leading banks of the country - themselves controlling nearly 60% of all banding capital and nearly half of all bank deposits - was foreign (Warren 1980, p 46.)
The position commonly adopted by the left is to deny that capitalism
is fulfilling its historical function in the developing countries. We
are told that capitalism is not developing the productive forces nor is
it destroying pre-capitalist conditions. The LDCs are supposedly
being underdeveloped by the world capitalist system. A
major part of
Imperialism, Pioneer of Capitalism is devoted to refuting these views.
The linchpin of these views is the modern theory of imperialism,
dependency and underdevelopment. Typical of the theorists in this area
are Paul Baran, Andre Gunder Frank and Samir Amin.
We are told that the people of the Third World have been getting
progressively worse off during the modern era (ie since the industrial
revolution) and have generally experienced a socio-economic and
cultural regression. Capitalism has developed, and continues to do so,
in a contradictory fashion, which generates at the same time
development in the centre and underdevelopment in the periphery.
The implication is that it is fruitless to expect underdeveloped
countries to repeat the stages of economic growth passed through by
modern developed capitalist economies whose classical capitalist
development arose out of pre-capitalist and feudal society. Hence, the
historical role of capitalism in these countries is finished, or at a
dead end. It is argued, moreover, that the achievement of political
independence has not significantly improved prospects of development in the periphery.
A number of arguments are put forward to support the above position. Warren picks out three as being particularly important.
(a) A drain of economic surplus from periphery to centre is
said to arise from the flow of profits from foreign investment in the
periphery back to the metropolitan country, and from unequal exchange
in trade.
Warren points out "that for such a drain to retard economic
development it must be an absolute drain not simply an unequal transaction that nevertheless leaves both sides better off than
before ...". For example, the comparison that people make between
profit outflow and capital inflow tends to be very misleading. Surplus
extraction under capitalism is not comparable to the plunder practiced
by the empires of antiquity.
Foreign investment creates the surplus (with the help of local labor of course) before it extracts it; and it does this by developing the productive forces. You can certainly criticise the form taken by foreign investment and trade, and argue that Third World countries would gain if they were better organised. What you cannot argue is that the wealth of Third World countries is being depleted.
Closely related to this surplus gain concept is the idea that
developed countries are better off than others because they have more
than their share of the world's resources. In other words the reason
why we have better plumbing than people in Bangladesh is because we
have more than our share of the world's supply of pipes and trained
plumbers.
Or to put it more generally, there is a fixed quantity of sone substance called prosperity and the more that goes to one lot of people the less there is for everybody else. This is a total failure to understand economic development as a process of economic accumulation. Its most negative effect is the implication that the interests of people in the developed and underdeveloped world are at loggerheads.
(b) The 'traditional' division of laborbetween centre and
periphery countries whereby the former produce manufactured goods
and the latter primary goods, is seen to be imposed by the centre on
the periphery and is a source of its backwardness.
Warren argues that the validity of the argument rests on two
assumptions, which he sets out to refute. These are first that there was
a possible and desirable alternative line of development to
primary-product, export-lead growth in the backward countries
concerned; and second, that the initial emphasis on the export of
primary products actually erected serious impediments to subsequent
diversification, especially along the lines of industrialisation.
(c) Imperialism or centre/periphery relations are said to
encourage the preservation of precapitalist modes of production. This
is discussed at two levels. First, there is the case where capitalist
production at one point encourages pre-capitalist production at another
point (eg, cotton production based on slavery). Here Warren correctly
argues that the destructive force of capitalist relations would far
outweigh any conserving tendencies.
Second, there is the claim that
imperialism has tended to ally itself with local feudalism at the
expense of progressive bourgeois forces. Warren replies thatthis is largely undercut by the almost universal
willingness of feudal classes to transform themselves, at least partly, into
capitalist industrialisers once conditions are ripe. Where
Warren falls short on this question in failing to emphasise that a thoroughly bourgeois revolution would far more successfully unleash capitalist development.
At a more general and theoretical level Warren attacks dependency theory on a number of grounds.
To begin with it is a static view. While a change in form over time tends to be conceded, the possibility of declining dependency is precluded. Moreover, changes in the centres of power is inadequately allowed for.
The theory is ahistorical in that it assumes the following:
(a) that there were latent suppressed historical alternatives to the
development that actually took place; (b) that the failure of
alternatives to materialise was primarily the result of external
imposition (colonial policy).
The theory is metaphysical in that it basically explains social
phenomenon in terms of external causes, rather than as an interaction
of both internal and external factors. (Mao spoke of external factors
as the conditions of change and internal factors as the basis of
change.) Dependency theorists would, for example, explain a country's
backwardness by the fact that foreign capital is only invested in enclaves or cash crops.
A more sensible approach would perhaps be to see cause and effect running the other way - because the country is backward these industries are the only opportunities for investment. The backwardness would then be explained essentially by internal factors, namely a social system and mode of production significantly inferior to, or historically less advanced than, capitalism in developed countries.
Dependency theory has a strong thread of nationalist utopia, which
establishes a set of thoroughly dubious criteria of what is good and
what is detrimental. The first blossoms of bourgeois society are
denounced simply as imperialist cultural penetration (coca cola
culture) serving the interests of the mutinationals and reinforcing
dependent status.
There is also the concept of articulated economy. Every country
has to have its own steel industry, for example. It is argued that if
you do not have the full range of industries you are trapped into some
narrow and enslaving international division of labor.
This last point touches on a major area of confusion, namely, the
distinction between dependence and interdependence. Warren says:
Since national economies are becoming increasingly interdependent, the meaning of dependence is even more elusive, not to say mystical.(Warren, 1980, p 182)
In fact with the increasing importance of international trade and
capital movement, it is often the case that dependence on trade and
foreign investment is a sign of economic development.
The last section of Warren's book provides extensive evidence that
considerable economic development has occurred in the Third Word during
the post-war period. It has been meteoric in comparison with that in
western countries. The western countries took centuries to emerge from
the Middle Ages and eventually achieve an industrial takeoff in the
nineteenth century.
On Lenin's views of imperialism
In Warren's opinion, the more recent theories of imperialism, such as underdevelopment and dependency are best regarded as post-war versions of the views expressed by Lenin in Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism,or at any rate stemming, or continuing, from where he left off. Warren also claimed that in this book Lenin was espousing views that were at variance with his earlier writings on the Narodniks and the role of capitalist development in Russia.
Here Warren is skating on thin ice. Much of his case rests on
Lenin's use of particular words, especially 'moribund', 'stagnant' and 'parasitic'. By
'moribund', Lenin is referring to the increasing
obsolescence of capitalism, exemplified most starkly by two world wars
and economic crises of the sort that hit in the 1930s and will hit
again in the future. He is not saying that social and economic
development ceases.
In his use of the word, 'stagnation', Lenin is not
saying that capitalism is no longer revolutionising the productive
forces - a proposition that would obviously be wrong. He is referring
to its increasing tardiness relative to a communist organisation of
production - the productive forces are outgrowing the capitalist mode
of production.
Warren tries to equate Lenin's description of monopoly
capital and imperialist countries as parasitic with the crude "surplus
drain' view . However, Lenin is not denying that the export of
capital
develops the productive forces in recipient countries; he is just
saying that the centralisation in the ownership of capital shows up
geographically.
Places such as London and New York have a far higher than average proportion of the world's bloodsuckers; they tend to be richer and their 'portfolios' span the world. When Lenin explicitly discussed the impact of imperialism on the then colonies, he said that it was developing the productive forces. Warren unjustifiably shrugs this off as lip service to Marxist orthodoxy.
Warren had a number of other criticisms of Lenin's position.
However, they are not central to our present discussion. He claims (a)
that capital exports have not increased in signifcance, (b) that Lenin
espoused underconsumptionism and (c) that inter-imperialist rivalry was
based on trade rather than competing capital. These and other issues
could perhaps be looked at on some other occasion in a fuller
discussion of Lenin's book.
Bibliography
Amin, S., Accumulation on a World Scale, New York, Monthly Review Press, 1974.
Avineri, S., ed., Karl Marx on Colonialism and Modernisation, New York, Anchor Books, 1969. Frank, A. G., Capitalism and Underdevelopment in LatinAmerica, Harmondsworth, Penguin Books, 1971.
Greene, F., The Enemy, Notes on Imperialism and Revolution, London, Jonathon Cape, 1970. One of the more readable and also more appalling renderings of the 'anti-imperialist' position.
Lenin, VI, 'On the So-Called Market Question' Collected Works, Vol. 1, Moscow, 1963.
----------- 'The economic content of Narodism and the criticism of it in Mr Struve's book', Collected Works, Vol. 7, Moscow, 1963.
-----------, Imperialism: the Highest Stage of Capitalism, Peking, Foreign Language Press.
Marx, K., Pre-Capitalist Economic Formations, London, Lawrence and Wishart, 1964.
----------- and Engels, F., Manifesto of the Communist Party, Peking, Foreign Language Press, 1968.
Warren, W., Imperialism and capitalist industrialisation
, in New Left Review (1973).
-----------, Imperialism and Neo-Colonialism
, British and Irish Communist Organisation (March 1977).
-----------, Nations and corporations
, in Times Literary Supplement, 1 November 1977..
-----------, Poverty and prosperity
in Times Literary Supplement, 12 December 1975.
-----------, Imperialism, Pioneer of Capitalism, Verso, 1980, 274 p.